Also Read
The 'marketplaces' of e-commerce parlance are 'exchanges' in financial economics. When you go to the National Stock Exchange, the liquidity that you obtain is directly made by the others who have placed orders at the NSE. Every order that you place at the NSE directly makes up its offering, which is the high liquidity of the order book. Without orders from users, there is no liquidity at the NSE. Access to other users is the NSE's offering. Once liquidity comes about at an existing exchange, it is very hard to compete with it. There are only a handful of examples, in world history, where a new exchange could take on an incumbent, if we exclude the US where peculiar financial regulations forced a fragmented market.
In the e-commerce world, the name of the game is to find an opportunity to setup a network effect, and ride it to glorious financial returns for the founders. From an economics point of view, there is something uncomfortable about the spectacle of one after another firm that is so keen to achieve a little impregnable monopoly, after which the normal rigours of competition do not apply.
Capitalism works because firms in competitive markets have to ceaselessly push the boulder up the hill. A constant stream of innovations are required for enhancing the product and cutting costs. The best that can be obtained by a good management team is reasonable returns on equity. This essence of capitalism, this Calvinist ethos, is lost once a monopoly is setup. Shareholders and managers then enjoy supernormal financial returns, and freedom from the pressure to constantly improve the product and reduce costs.
In network industries, the profit motive encourages managers and investors to do many perverse things. As an example, speed is more important than product quality. The firm with 2,000 users beats the one with 200 users. A weak product that's released early wins when compared with a great product that's released late: there is a bias in favour of speed and not product quality. Another odd thing is the role of capital. Money has become the raw material. The firm that subsidises users on a bigger scale gets more users, and then the network effects take off. Competitive advantage is then about obtaining more and cheaper capital from the global financial system, and not building a better product. Put these together, and the sloppy product that's backed by the big money wins.
The computer revolution offers great opportunities to improve products and processes in all industries. Too many technologists and investors are, however, too high to engage in this slow hard work. The game has become one of finding the quickest path to network effects, after which you have a monopoly. The reward for this is supernormal financial returns and laziness. The spectacle of young men and women, who are imbued with a get-rich-quick ethos, and dreams of laziness, is disturbing. "Economists need to reinvent competition policy so as to address the market failure, of market power, in this landscape."
The writer is a professor at National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi