Business Standard

<b>Daniel Gros:</b> An unfounded fear of deflation

Image

Daniel Gros
Central banks throughout the developed world have been overwhelmed by the fear of deflation. They shouldn't be: The fear is unfounded, and the obsession with it is damaging.

Click here to connect with us on WhatsApp

Japan is a poster child for the fear. In 2013, decades of falling prices prompted the Bank of Japan to embark on an unprecedented monetary offensive. But while headline inflation increased for a while, the factors driving that increase - a competitive depreciation of the yen and a tax increase - did not last long. Now, the country is slipping back into near-deflation - a point that panicked headlines underscore.
 

But, contrary to the impression created by media reports, the Japanese economy is far from moribund. Unemployment has virtually disappeared; the employment rate continues to reach new highs; and disposable income per capita is rising steadily. In fact, even during Japan's so-called "lost decades," per capita income grew by as much as it did in the United States and Europe, and the employment rate rose, suggesting that deflation may not be quite as nefarious as central bankers seem to believe.

In the US and Europe, there is also little sign of an economic calamity resulting from central banks' failure to reach their inflation targets. Growth remains solid, if not spectacular, and employment is rising.

There are two problems with central banks' current approach. First, they are focused on consumer prices, which is the wrong target. Consumer prices are falling for a simple reason: energy and other raw material prices have declined by more than half in the last two years. The decline is therefore temporary, and central banks should look past it, much as they looked past the increase in consumer prices when oil prices were surging.

Instead, central banks should focus on the rate of revenue increase, measured in nominal gross domestic product (GDP) growth; that is, after all, what matters for highly indebted governments and enterprises. By this measure, there is no deflation: The GDP price index (called GDP deflator) in developed countries is increasing by 1-1.5 per cent, on average. In the eurozone, it is rising at 1.2 per cent. This may fall short of the European Central Bank's target of "below but close to 2 per cent," but not by a margin substantial enough to justify the ECB's increasingly aggressive use of monetary instruments to stimulate the economy.

Moreover, nominal GDP growth exceeds the long-term interest rate. When, as is usually the case, the long-term interest rate is higher than the GDP growth rate, the wealthy may accumulate wealth faster than the rest of the economy - a point made by the economist Thomas Piketty. But today, nominal GDP growth far exceeds average long-term interest rates (which, in some countries, include risk premia of up to 100 basis points) - even in the eurozone, where nominal GDP growth is expected to reach about three per cent this year. This means that financing conditions are as favourable as they were at the peak of the credit boom in 2007, and much better than they have been at any other point in the last 20 years.

One might expect this evidence to compel central bankers to rethink their current concerns about deflation. But they remain committed to pursuing their inflation targets, convinced that even a slight bout of deflation could initiate a downward spiral, with falling demand causing prices to decline further. This is their second mistake.

Of course, a deflationary spiral is possible, and its consequences could be serious. If real interest rates were significantly positive, demand could plummet, pushing down prices to the point that it becomes impossible for borrowers to service their debts. Such a spiral contributed to the Great Depression in the US in the 1930s, with prices falling, in some years, by some 20-30 per cent.

But we are nowhere near such conditions today. In fact, nominal interest rates are at zero, while the broadest price indices are increasing, albeit gently. Given that financing conditions are so favourable, it is not surprising that domestic demand has remained robust, allowing unemployment to return to pre-crisis lows almost everywhere.

The eurozone is the only large developed economy where unemployment remains substantial, and thus the only economy where the case could be made for a downside risk of deflation. But even in the eurozone, GDP growth is slightly above its (admittedly very meagre) potential, so that the remaining output gap is being closed gradually.

Furthermore, the only reason why unemployment remains high in the eurozone is that the labour-force participation rate has continued to increase throughout the recession; and, indeed, employment is returning to pre-crisis levels. This is the exact opposite of what the deflation hawks warn about. The popular "discouraged worker" hypothesis holds that a slide into deflation is costly, because a long recession induces workers to leave the labour force altogether. That is simply not the case in Europe today.

The evidence is clear. Developed-economy central banks should overcome their irrational fear of a deflationary spiral, and stop trying desperately to stimulate demand. Otherwise, they will find themselves with massively expanded balance sheets, and very little to show for it.

The writer is Director of the Centre for European Policy Studies
Disclaimer: These are personal views of the writer. They do not necessarily reflect the opinion of www.business-standard.com or the Business Standard newspaper

Don't miss the most important news and views of the day. Get them on our Telegram channel

First Published: Apr 25 2016 | 9:47 PM IST

Explore News